class: center, middle, inverse, title-slide .title[ # Choice over Time: Introduction ] .subtitle[ ## EC404; Spring 2024 ] .author[ ### Prof. Ben Bushong ] .date[ ### Last updated February 20, 2024 ] --- layout: true <div class="msu-header"></div> <div style = "position:fixed; visibility: hidden"> `$$\require{color}\definecolor{yellow}{rgb}{1, 0.8, 0.16078431372549}$$` `$$\require{color}\definecolor{orange}{rgb}{0.96078431372549, 0.525490196078431, 0.203921568627451}$$` `$$\require{color}\definecolor{MSUgreen}{rgb}{0.0784313725490196, 0.52156862745098, 0.231372549019608}$$` </div> <script type="text/x-mathjax-config"> MathJax.Hub.Config({ TeX: { Macros: { yellow: ["{\\color{yellow}{#1}}", 1], orange: ["{\\color{orange}{#1}}", 1], MSUgreen: ["{\\color{MSUgreen}{#1}}", 1] }, loader: {load: ['[tex]/color']}, tex: {packages: {'[+]': ['color']}} } }); </script> <style> .yellow {color: #FFCC29;} .orange {color: #F58634;} .MSUGreen {color: #14853B;} </style> --- class: MSU # Overview of Topic 2 ## Topic 2: ### Intertemporal Choice or Making Choices Over Time Many interesting questions in economics involve choice over time: - How do people allocate their wealth between current consumption and future consumption? - How do people decide when to work on tasks? - For goods that yield short-term consumption utility but generate negative consequences in the long-term---e.g., alcohol, cigarettes, potato chips---how do people trade off the short-term benefits vs. the long-term costs? --- class: MSU # Overview of Topic 2 The standard model ("exponential discounting") assumes: 1. People treat time in a relatively even-handed manner. 2. People carry out their plans. 3. People know what they'll like in the future. --- class: MSU # Today's Lecture ### Warm-Up: Interest Rates, Compounding, PDV Let's understand some of the precursors to the standard model and (quickly) do some example problems. (This is a great time to ask questions.) ### The Standard Model (Today + Thursday) --- class: MSU # Interest Rates and Compounding **Example A:** Suppose you put $1000 into a bank account that pays 10% interest per year. - After 1 year, you'll have $1000 * (1.10) = $1100 . - After 2 years, you'll have $1100 * (1.10)= $1210 . - After 3 years, you'll have $1210 * (1.10)= $1331 . -- More generally: If you put `\(P\)` into a bank account that pays interest rate `\(r\)` per year, its future value in `\(T\)` years will be `\(P\ast(1+r)^{T}\)` . --- class: MSU # Interest Rates and Compounding ### Definitions (easy; hopefully not new) *Compound interest* is interest paid on past interest earned. -- *Compounding* is earning interest on past interest earned. -- The **frequency of compounding** is the frequency at which interest is credited to your account (after which it's starts earning compound interest). -- Our example above implicitly assumed yearly compounding. Of course, we could have more frequent compounding.... --- class: MSU # Interest Rates and Compounding **Example B:** Suppose you put $1000 into a bank account that pays a 10% annual interest rate that is compounded every six months. Because a 10% annual interest rate implies a 5% semi-annual interest rate: - After 6 months, you'll have `\(1000 \ast (1.05)= 1050\)` . - After 1 year, you'll have `\(1050 \ast (1.05)= 1102.50\)` . -- **Example C:** Suppose you put $1000 into a bank account that pays a 10% annual interest rate that is compounded every month. Because a 10% annual interest rate implies a `\(0.8\bar{3}\)` % monthly interest rate: - After 1 year, you'll have `\((1000)\ast(1.008\bar{3})^{12}=1104.71\)` . --- class: MSU # Interest Rates and Compounding More generally, if you put `\(P\)` into a bank account that pays an annual interest rate of `\(r\)` that is compounded `\(n\)` times per year: - Its future value after 1 year will be `\((P)\ast (1+r/n)^{n}\)` . - Its future value after `\(T\)` years will be `\((P)\ast \left[ (1+r/n)^{n} \right] ^{T}\)` . -- - Note: For continuous compounding, `\(\lim_{n\rightarrow \infty}(1+r/n)^{n}=e^{r}\)` and `\(\lim_{n\rightarrow \infty }\left[ (1+r/n)^{n}\right] ^{T}=e^{rT}\)` . --- class: MSU # Discrete-Time Models Suppose there is some set of periods `\(0,1,2,...,T\)` (perhaps `\(T=\infty\)` ). - Note: The length of a period might be one year, one month, one day, or whatever is most appropriate for the particular application. Suppose there is a per-period interest rate `\(r\)`, and interest is compounded every period. If `\(P_{t}\)` is the principal in your bank account in period `\(t\)`, then: - `\(P_{1}=(1+r)\ast P_{0}\)` - `\(P_{2}=(1+r)^{2}\ast P_{0}\)` - `\(P_{t}=(1+r)^{t}\ast P_{0}\)` - `\(P_{6}=(1+r)\ast P_{5}\)` - `\(P_{6}=(1+r)^{4}\ast P_{2}\)` - `\(P_{t+x}=(1+r)^{x}\ast P_{t}\)` --- class: MSU # Present Discounted Value (PDV) Suppose that you will be paid $1100 one year from today. If the market interest rate is 10% (and yearly compounding), how much is this future payment be worth to you now? -- We can answer this question by asking how much you could borrow now such that you would have to pay back exactly $1100 in one year. - Answer: $1000 --- because `\((1.10)\ast(1000)=1100\)` . -- **Definition**: Given per-period interest rate `\(r\)`, the *present discounted value* (or sometimes just *present value* or *PDV*) of `\(P\)` to be paid `\(T\)` periods in the future is `$$\frac{P}{(1+r)^{T}}$$` --- class: MSU # Present Discounted Value (PDV) Some `\(PDV\)` 's for `\(P=1000\)` and yearly compounding: | `\(r\)` | 1 Year | 2 Years | 3 Years | 10 Years | 20 Years | |:---:|:------:|:-------:|:-------:|:--------:|:--------:| | 3% | $971 | $943 | $915 | $744 | $554 | | 4% | $962 | $925 | $889 | $676 | $456 | | 5% | $952 | $907 | $864 | $614 | $377 | | 6% | $943 | $890 | $840 | $558 | $312 | | 7% | $935 | $873 | $816 | $508 | $258 | --- class: MSU # PDV of a Stream of Payoffs Suppose that you will be paid $1100 one year from today, another $1100 two years from today, and yet another $1100 three years from today. -- If the market interest rate is 10% (and yearly compounding), how much is this stream of payoffs worth to you now? **Answer:** Add up the individual `\(PDV\)` bit-by-bit: $$PDV=\frac{\$1100}{(1.10)}+\frac{\$1100}{(1.10)^{2}}+\frac{\$1100}{(1.10)^{3}}=\$2735.54.$$ -- More generally: Given per-period interest rate `\(r\)`, a stream of future revenues `\((R_{1},R_{2},...,R_{N})\)` (where revenue `\(R_{n}\)` is received in period `\(n\)`) has a present discounted value of: `$$PDV=\frac{R_{1}}{(1+r)}+\frac{R_{2}}{(1+r)^{2}}+...+\frac{R_{N}}{(1+r)^{N}}.$$` --- class: MSU # Time-Varying Interest Rates **Definition:** The *period-* `\(t\)` *interest rate* `\(r_{t}\)` is the interest rate between period `\(t\)` and period `\(t+1\)`. In other words, if in period `\(t\)` your principal is `\(P_{t}\)`, then in period `\(t+1\)` it becomes `\(P_{t+1}=(1+r_{t})P_{t}\)`. -- Hence, if `\(P_{t}\)` is the principal in your bank account in period `\(t\)`, and if your bank account pays per-period interest rates `\((r_{t},r_{t+1},...)\)`, then: - `\(P_{t+1}=(1+r_{t})P_{t}\)`. - `\(P_{t+2}=(1+r_{t+1})P_{t+1}=(1+r_{t+1})(1+r_{t})P_{t}\)`. - `\(P_{t+3}=(1+r_{t+2})P_{t+2}=(1+r_{t+2})(1+r_{t+1})(1+r_{t})P_{t}\)`. - And so on.... --- class: MSU # Time-Varying Interest Rates Given per-period interest rates `\((r_{t},r_{t+1},...)\)`, a stream of future revenues `\((R_{t+1},R_{t+2},R_{t+3})\)` has a present discounted value of `$$PDV = \frac{R_{t+1}}{(1+r_{t})}+\frac{R_{t+2}}{(1+r_{t})(1+r_{t+1})}+\frac{R_{t+3}}{(1+r_{t})(1+r_{t+1})(1+r_{t+2})}.$$` --- class: inverseMSU # End of Warm-Up As always, you will *not* need to memorize any of these equations. But we want to remind ourselves how to think about choices across time. - How do you assess today versus tomorrow? - What is the "correct" weight to put on money today versus money tomorrow? - What determines this tradeoff? We'll explore these questions (and many more) coming up.